Skip to main content

Flawed Theory and the Endowment Effect

Image: Youkai Chou
It's a happy day. Through some divine stroke of luck you have found yourself with two free tickets to the Rugby Sevens / insert-event-you-want-to-attend. What should you do? Is it a better idea to sell your coveted tickets to the highest bidder or to take along a friend and have a good time? What's a reasonable way to think about this decidedly pleasant dilemma? Homo economicus, the imaginary friend of every economist, may have some advice for you.

So who is Homo economicus? He is the relentlessly optimising, perfectly rational, purely self-interested character who serves as a model for human behaviour. Numerous core economic theories are formulated through the study of how this creature would behave and interact under certain conditions.

Fortunately, for economists and everyone else, humans are indeed often rational actors. For instance, the central economic tenet that, all other things being equal, an increase in the price of a good or service will result in a decrease of the quantity demanded holds up pretty well. Thus, a model predicated on the assumption of human rationality certainly has its merits. 

However, such a model is prone to grossly misrepresenting the behaviour of average humans. Homo economicus does not procrastinate (Hyperbolic Discounting) and never makes a bad decision. Homo economicus has no emotions. Homo economicus would never donate to a charity, help a friend, or contribute to the public good. (Why be so extravagant as to help others when you could help yourself instead?) Homo economicus, if he did exist, would not be human. Some of his traits, such as the ability to perceive information without biases, would definitely be desirable. On the whole, however, he would be something of a cold, calculating monster. 


As a result of their dependence on human rationality, many economic theories do not fare well when tested against empirical realities. The efficient market hypothesis (EMH), for example, postulates that asset prices are accurate reflections of the available information, and are therefore "correct". Should anomalies occur in the market price, they will be instantly identified and removed through arbitrage. The EMH gained a lot of traction in the investment world, and was widely held in reverence. But if the efficient market hypothesis is to be entirely believed, stock market bubbles are theoretically impossible! Emerging bubbles would be identified and quickly eliminated by "smarter" investors. Such a conclusion is demonstrably incorrect. Bubbles in asset prices have always occurred and always will occur. Investors are regularly overconfident and vulnerable to overreaction. Further, you can take the EMH to another equally ridiculous logical extreme and claim that if stocks were perfectly priced there would be no market: no one would trade. In a world of purely rational, faultlessly informed people, who would be willing to buy an asset someone else found necessary to sell? 
Image: Time
For economics to offer more insightful and widely applicable theories, it must move beyond a model that assumes unbounded rationality. Behavioural economics, a field that combines economics and psychology, focusses on studying Homo sapiens, and how they—well, we—differ from the purely rational beings economics has long been obsessed with. 

One of the findings made by behavioural economists is that people exhibit what's called the "endowment effect", they value things they own more than things they could own, but do not yet possess. In other words, we are inclined to demand much more to sell a particular object than we would offer in order to buy it. 

The endowment effect was famously demonstrated in an experiment involving mugs and Cornell students. Researchers Daniel Kahneman, Jack Knetsch, and Richard Thaler arbitrarily selected some students from a class and gave them an ordinary mug from the Cornell gift shop. A "market" was then set up for these mugs. Each student with a mug was asked to discreetly record the minimum price at which they would sell; the students not part of this fortunate group were asked to record the maximum price at which they would buy. Strangely, the average offering price was $7 per mug, but the average bid was only $3. The mugs were worth more than twice as much to those who had them than to those who didn't! 

A more striking example is seen in a study which found that people would pay only $2,000 to lower their chance of death by 1/1000, but would demand $500,000 to increase it by the same amount. (Thaler, 2015) Economic theory and common logic demand that the "buying" and "selling" prices be identical in both cases: such results seem preposterous. Yet, due to the endowment effect, a mug can be worth at least $7 and at most $3. And avoiding an increased risk of death is worth no more than $2,000 but no less than $500,000!

Now back to those Sevens tickets. What we have learnt suggests that we will likely overvalue the tickets merely because they are free. Our perception of the opportunity cost—what we sacrifice in order to use the tickets—is warped because we think of the tickets as "free gifts." However, from an economic standpoint, those tickets are anything but free. The tickets could sell for upwards of HKD 5,000, money which could serve countless other purposes. To adjust for the endowment effect, a more sensible way to think of something "free" is to ask yourself how much money you'd be willing to part with to obtain it. Would you pay HKD 5,000 for a weekend at the Sevens?

(As an aside, it would be interesting to see the difference between what an average student would pay for a chance to turn a B to an A, as opposed to what they would demand in order to stand the risk of having an A turn into a B!) 

Perhaps the best outcome would be for economics to advance current theoretical understanding by assimilating psychological insights into the fallibility of human rationality. Economists have long studied Homo Economicus. Now, they should study Humans too. 

For those interested, there's a neat Freakonomics podcast on what it would be like to live as Homo economicus:
If you want to know more about behavioural economics, Richard Thaler's recently published a book, Misbehaving, is a great read.

Comments

  1. Though many terms are beyond my ready understanding,I entirely agree that human beings are not only rational beings but are greatly influenced by human psychology.One may therefore be more inclined to spend an interesting weekend with a good friend than to earn $ 5000 by selling the two free tickets,even though a purely rational person may take the opposite decision. However psychology plays its role only when basic human needs are fulfilled. That's why we do not find marginal persons dabbling in stock market.
    Well presented!
    Love
    Nanaji

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Thank you for the insightful comment, Nanaji! Glad you enjoyed the post. It is indeed interesting to observe instances in which humans stray from rational behaviour and the particular conditions under which such an effect is most apparent.
      Love
      Yash

      Delete
  2. This comment has been removed by the author.

    ReplyDelete
  3. I think you have a misunderstanding here. The purpose of assuming full rationality is not to *explain* human behaviour, but to *describe* its outcomes. Regardless of how individuals really are, economists find that assuming perfect rationality is the best predictor of how humans act in a group. It fits the data best.

    At the end of the day, it doesn't really matter whether you feel benevolent today, or whether I go for that short term reward (in terms of economics). The reality is that the actions that we end up taking by and large match up with what rational economics would expect.

    (Sorry, I removed the earlier comment, as it was badly phrased)

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Thanks for your comment, Jonathan!

      I agree that the practical usefulness of economics is in its ability to describe the outcomes of, instead of simply explain, human behaviour. The assumption of rationality certainly has merits and is appropriate in a broad range of situations, as I mentioned in my article. However, it is precisely in describing the outcomes of human behaviour where the rational agent model can be insufficient. This is particularly true with regards to the fact that individuals indeed do not demonstrate consistent preferences and are influenced by "supposedly irrelevant factors" such as loss aversion and the "availability bias"—our tendency to only reference information that is easily retrievable.

      However, two examples, one concerned with our individual behaviour and one with our behaviour in a group, can also demonstrate "long term" shortcomings of a model that assumes rationality.

      Saving for retirement is a fantastic example in which short term bad choices aggregate to a problem of much larger scale. A rational agent would, through some means or another, would always save enough for a retirement deemed satisfactory. This hypothesis is inconsistent with reality. Furthermore, a behavioural approach to saving has been empirically shown to increase savings rates considerably, an outcome that would not be logical under an assumption of rationality.
      If you scroll down to "Saving" on this link, a more eloquent explanation is provided: http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/BehavioralEconomics.html

      Financial markets provide an excellent example of how the actions of a group also defy rationality. Two of the core tenets of the efficient market hypothesis are that stock markets are fundamentally unpredictable and investors "price in" all available information. This finding is untenable considering the presence of stock bubbles as well as various research findings showing that stocks that outperform over a five year period consistently underperform in the subsequent period, and vice versa. This suggests that the market as a whole can be susceptible to irrational overreaction. Additionally, it has been consistently shown that the close-ended funds—those which are tradable on the market—trade at significant discounts to their NAV, a result that defies an assumption of rationality in the overall market.

      Delete

Post a Comment

Popular posts from this blog

On Myanmar

This is adapted from a paper I wrote for my Comparative Politics class at Harvard . A Friendless People Thousands have been killed. Hundreds of thousands have fled. They are a people without a home, much less a state. Such is the plight of the Rohingya, whom a UN spokesperson once called the most friendless people in the world. The United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights has called the situation a “textbook example of ethnic cleansing” (“UN”). This latest wave of state-sponsored violence follows a series of attacks by militants—a small insurgent group, the Arakan Rohingya Salvation Army (ARSA)—in August on Myanmarese military outposts. The brutal military crackdown is ostensibly targeted at insurgents. Yet, it is unmistakably civilians who are bearing the brunt of the violence, with the UN High Commissioner calling the response “clearly disproportionate” and “without regard for basic principles of international law” (“UN”). The approach of ethnic institutionalism has

The Tax Reform India Needs

Image: Tizi A version of this article also appeared in the South China Morning Post's Young Post on Thursday, May 5.  http://yp.scmp.com/news/features/article/103398/india%E2%80%99s-economy-taking-right-steps-goods-and-service-tax India’s current prime minister, Narendra Modi, was elected in 2014 on his economic credentials and the promise that he would bring to the nation the same prosperity he brought, as chief minister, to his home state of Gujarat.  The keystone of Modi’s economic policy is a nationwide goods-and-service tax (GST), intended to streamline the myriad state and central-government levies currently encumbering business in the country.   Under the prevailing tax regime, multiple layers of tax are imposed on the same good, and interstate trade is complicated by varying tax rates between states. Transporting goods across state borders can entail long waiting times to resolve tax matters, and the plethora of obscure charges leaves ample room for co

Where Lurks the Next Crisis?

Photo: SCMP Optimism flows freely through the markets today. Asset prices are at record highs: investors are happier than ever to throw money at barely profitable technology companies, debt issuances from dubious companies and volatile governments, and anything blockchain related—from Bitcoin to Ethereum to Insanecoin, which does actually exist.     Most observers think that the coin mania is a bubble waiting to burst. But bears have been calling the whole market a bubble for a while, predicting an end to the years-long economic recovery and stock market boom. The old joke goes that economists have called seven of the last two recessions. It still rings true. Doomsayers have been convinced of a market crash since the post-recession recovery had barely gotten on its legs. But with things as they are today, are we on a path toward crisis?   I will not engage in the perilous business of trying to predict when the next economic downturn or market tumble will occur. Any such p