Skip to main content

Ruffled Feathers: Poultry and Development

Image: Pixabay
The humble chicken, normally not much discussed beyond the dining table, assumed an unlikely prominence in development circles this past year. The rise of this avian began with a post by Bill Gates on his influential “gatesnotes” blog. In it, he advocates the distribution of chickens in sub-Saharan Africa as a means of alleviating extreme poverty—improving the lot of people making less than US$2 a day. 

Gates argues that chickens are “easy and inexpensive to take care of”, requiring only cheap vaccines and having no special feeding needs. He additionally claims chickens are a solid investment because of their relatively high market price—he cities the figure of US$5 as being the standard in West Africa—and their ability to frequently reproduce. 

Ultimately, he calculates that a woman who raises a flock of chickens could generate income north of US$1000 annually, all while also combating malnutrition within the family and empowering herself as an earner—Gates notes that chickens are seen in many cultures as “woman’s animal”, ensuring that much of the proceeds of rearing chickens will accrue to women. 

Gates’ relatively brief post perhaps deliberately glossed over practical considerations and in-depth economic analysis. It soon sparked a lively debate within the development community, a debate that has spanned everything from practical economic considerations to the very philosophical core of development economics.

In response to Gates’ analysis, Chris Blattman, a prominent development economist at the University of Chicago, wrote an open letter critical of the proposal. Blattman first takes issue with an uncharacteristic oversight of fundamental economic theory on Gates’ part. 

Gates casually assumes that the prevailing market value of a chicken would be maintained even after the distribution of chickens to hundreds of thousands (if not more) of families in sub-Saharan Africa. This clearly cannot be the case. Gates’ policy would entail a huge increase in the supply of chickens, which would almost necessarily reduce the equilibrium price of poultry. The income gains to poor women are thus unlikely to be anywhere near US$1000 per year.  

The more constructive aspects of Blattman’s argument are divided into two key themes: cash and experiments. He belongs to the camp of development economists who believe that among the best poverty alleviation prescriptions is simply distributing cash effectively. Such handouts are something Gates has vocally opposed in the past in favour of training programs and similar solutions that build human capital more directly. 

Blattman postulates that the versatility of cash means means that it is more likely to be used by the poor in an optimal manner—as opposed to the “one-size-fits-all” nature of a chicken distribution program. Bolstering his argument, Blattman notes that there is a strong body of evidence suggesting that it is not a dearth of investment opportunities but rather limited access to capital that prevents the poor from pursuing profitable business opportunities. 

He concedes that there is as yet no conclusive evidence to suggest that the poor would be better off with cash handouts than with programs such as chicken distribution, but counters that the distribution of chickens, and the training costs associated with teaching families how to succeed at raising them, would fundamentally make the program financially wasteful. Multiple studies are cited showing that the disbursement of cash is very significantly more cost-effective than are training programs or the distribution livestock. Ultimately, if cash is what people want, chickens can easily be sold. 

In the second part of his letter, Blattman advocates a more empirical and experimental approach—referred to within the field as “Randomized Control Trials” (RCTs). Essentially, he proposes a controlled experiment involved 6-8 different treatments, including Gates’ chicken idea, tested against a group given only cash and a control group that is left alone. The RCT method has gained much popularity among the development economics community, and is often considered among the most creditable method of establishing policy efficacy. 

Yet, it was not long before debate on the topic extended beyond practical efficacy and into moral and philosophical perspectives on development research and methodology. Lant Pritchett, economist at Harvard University’s Kennedy School of Government, takes a more institutional approach toward development. He is deeply skeptical of marginal fixes. In short, as Pritchett sees it, Gates and Blatmann are wasting time. 

Pritchett’s view is that the most worthwhile research would centre on determining how to craft institutions that will foster growth in Africa and maximise human potential. He insists that this is the only method of generating long-term growth. Pritchett puts forward an Impassioned defence of research and policy institutions like the World Bank. He maintains that it is their work on the fundamentals of economic growth that make the maximum impact by contributing to a body of knowledge on the subject.  

In response to Pritchett, Blatmann laments that prioritising long-term growth research over more immediate fixes holds only in a purely utilitarian perspective—which would advocate undermining today’s generation in benefit  bolstering knowledge about how to improve future generations. Blatmann acknowledges that there are core philosophical differences within development theory. Logic and analysis alone cannot resolve the gulf between differing ideologies. He reasons that we have an obligation to combat the suffering in the present, and that it is noteworthy to be part of an effort to ensure that the tens of billions being poured into international aid each year are spent well. 

With all its complexities, the optimal path toward development is impossible to reduce to one theory or a single set of approaches. What constitutes development is itself a topic of extended dispute among scholars in the field. Strong theoretical foundations for models of development, rigorous empirical experimentation, critical analysis of theories and objectives, and learning from past failures will all be critical. The uncertainty surrounding paths toward development take nothing away from the fact that it is vital work, with the ability to radically transform the fortunes of billions in the present and the future. 

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

On Myanmar

This is adapted from a paper I wrote for my Comparative Politics class at Harvard . A Friendless People Thousands have been killed. Hundreds of thousands have fled. They are a people without a home, much less a state. Such is the plight of the Rohingya, whom a UN spokesperson once called the most friendless people in the world. The United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights has called the situation a “textbook example of ethnic cleansing” (“UN”). This latest wave of state-sponsored violence follows a series of attacks by militants—a small insurgent group, the Arakan Rohingya Salvation Army (ARSA)—in August on Myanmarese military outposts. The brutal military crackdown is ostensibly targeted at insurgents. Yet, it is unmistakably civilians who are bearing the brunt of the violence, with the UN High Commissioner calling the response “clearly disproportionate” and “without regard for basic principles of international law” (“UN”). The approach of ethnic institutionalism has

The Tax Reform India Needs

Image: Tizi A version of this article also appeared in the South China Morning Post's Young Post on Thursday, May 5.  http://yp.scmp.com/news/features/article/103398/india%E2%80%99s-economy-taking-right-steps-goods-and-service-tax India’s current prime minister, Narendra Modi, was elected in 2014 on his economic credentials and the promise that he would bring to the nation the same prosperity he brought, as chief minister, to his home state of Gujarat.  The keystone of Modi’s economic policy is a nationwide goods-and-service tax (GST), intended to streamline the myriad state and central-government levies currently encumbering business in the country.   Under the prevailing tax regime, multiple layers of tax are imposed on the same good, and interstate trade is complicated by varying tax rates between states. Transporting goods across state borders can entail long waiting times to resolve tax matters, and the plethora of obscure charges leaves ample room for co

Where Lurks the Next Crisis?

Photo: SCMP Optimism flows freely through the markets today. Asset prices are at record highs: investors are happier than ever to throw money at barely profitable technology companies, debt issuances from dubious companies and volatile governments, and anything blockchain related—from Bitcoin to Ethereum to Insanecoin, which does actually exist.     Most observers think that the coin mania is a bubble waiting to burst. But bears have been calling the whole market a bubble for a while, predicting an end to the years-long economic recovery and stock market boom. The old joke goes that economists have called seven of the last two recessions. It still rings true. Doomsayers have been convinced of a market crash since the post-recession recovery had barely gotten on its legs. But with things as they are today, are we on a path toward crisis?   I will not engage in the perilous business of trying to predict when the next economic downturn or market tumble will occur. Any such p