Skip to main content

Pioneer of the Behavioral Revolution Wins Economics Nobel

Photo: Reuters/SCMP
This year’s Nobel Prize in Economics was awarded to Richard Thaler, a University of Chicago economist who pioneered the pathbreaking field of behavioral economics—a discipline at the intersection of economics and psychology. 

Economists have traditionally eschewed psychology in their models of human behavior, insisting that humans are fundamentally rational. That is to say much of mainstream economic theory is premised on the notion that humans systemically make choices leading to optimal self-benefit, and that all decisions we make can be defended on purely logical grounds. 

This assumption has been problematic; many observable economic and behavioral phenomena sit uneasily with explanations grounded solely within the realm of rationality. Of course, the simple statement that humans are irrational does not provide much value to economics in and of itself: models cannot automatically incorporate the notion. For irrationality to be academically useful, it is essential that behavioral biases be measurable, predictable and durable. 

That is where Thaler—and fellow researchers like Daniel Kahneman, who won the Nobel for Economics in 2002, and the late Amos Tversky—made his most important contributions. Thaler’s explorations of such phenomena began in the early 1970s, at a time when economics sought to distinguish itself from other social sciences by a rigorous application of mathematical principles and formal models. 

During his time in graduate school, and early in his career as an economist, Thaler began building a list of behaviors he observed that were fundamentally inconsistent with assumptions of rationality. Among his favorite was the observation that ownership increases the perceived value of a good, what Thaler labeled the “endowment effect”. That is to say that given a particular good, you somewhat absurdly demand more to sell your unit of the good than you would offer to buy the same good from someone else. Unsurprisingly, Thaler’s work brought him little instant popularity within the profession. He often mentions that his thesis adviser noted of Thaler’s graduate student career that “We did not expect much of him.”  

Within academic circles, Thaler’s most cited paper discusses whether the stock market overreact. An affirmation of market overreaction fundamentally undermines a core tenet of orthodox financial economics, the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH). The EMH theorizes that markets always perfectly and instantaneously incorporate all relevant information about a stock, demonstrating pure rationality. Thaler ultimately found that psychological biases do indeed result in pricing anomalies within the market. Following this, a colleague at the University of Chicago, a strong proponent of the EMH, refused even to make eye contact with Thaler for decades. 

In an interview with the New York Times, Thaler said he was perhaps best known for his work on “mental accounting”. Classical economics assumes that money is fungible; in simplest terms, that “money is money”—spending decisions should not be impacted by the source of the money or by emotional factors that earmark money for use only in particular ways. However, Thaler discovered that people irrationally allocate spending based on “mental accounts”—for example, by refusing to divert money from a savings fund for holidays to pay down high-interest credit card debt. 

Although behavioral economics remains contentious among some economic purists, Thaler’s persistent and rigorous work eventually won him acclaim in the academic community and brought him a high public profile. He was elected president of the American Economic Association in 2015. 

His popular recognition was elevated by his work with Harvard scholar Cass Sunstein, with whom Thaler co-authored Nudge. I read “Nudge” a couple years ago, and was perhaps most struck by its philosophical prescriptions for public policy. In matter of policy, “Nudge” advocates for what its authors refer to as “libertarian paternalism”. 

Pure libertarianism advocates for the preservation of individual choice at all costs, and abhors the limitation of freedom even if it is in the individual’s supposed best interest. Paternalism, on the other hand, holds the view that individual freedom can and should be restricted to promote “objectively” superior outcomes. 

How are these seemingly opposed ideologies reconciled? The idea put forth by Thaler and Sunstein is that predictable behavioral tendencies can be exploited to preserve individual choice while “nudging” people to make a decision that may be more personally and socially optimal. The book was deeply influential, even inspiring the creation of a “Nudge Unit” in the British government, which has been involved with policy prescriptions targeted at everything from raising tax collection to increasing organ donation rates.

“Misbehaving”, which Thaler wrote in 2015, further expounds upon his career and the development of behavioral economics. In the book, Thaler tears into the assumption that we live in a world of perfectly rational beings, homo economicus or Econs, as he somewhat mockingly refers to the beings of economic theory. He also criticizes the intellectual arrogance of economics as a field, noting that it is untenably resistant to integration with other social sciences. As someone greatly interested in economics, the book had a strong impact on me. It was an anecdote in “Misbehaving” that led me to write a research paper examining the rationality of punters in Hong Kong’s horse-race betting market.

Richard Thaler helped lead the charge for the integration of economics with other social sciences, particularly psychology. Because of his work, economics, fundamentally the study of human behavior, is just a bit more human. In “Misbehaving” Thaler espouses a vision that behavioral economics will cease to exist as a distinct field. Instead, he hopes that behavioral insights will become part and parcel of economic orthodoxy. With this Nobel, he is a step closer to that vision. 

Comments

  1. Each variant will differ in a number of} ways to make 우리카지노 your mobile expertise thrilling. You will find classic choices corresponding to European roulette and American roulette that observe the same rules aside from the variety of 0s on the table. There’s pinball roulette that doesn’t make use of a wheel at all however still uses the same basics as European roulette. And there’s multi-wheel roulette that’s excellent for players who wish to take pleasure in a fast-paced expertise by placing bets on quantity of} wheels at once. Just remember to read by way of the bonus phrases of the provide you’re contemplating as the site requires players to make use of El Royale Casino promo codes to be able to} claim a bonus.

    ReplyDelete

Post a Comment

Popular posts from this blog

On Myanmar

This is adapted from a paper I wrote for my Comparative Politics class at Harvard . A Friendless People Thousands have been killed. Hundreds of thousands have fled. They are a people without a home, much less a state. Such is the plight of the Rohingya, whom a UN spokesperson once called the most friendless people in the world. The United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights has called the situation a “textbook example of ethnic cleansing” (“UN”). This latest wave of state-sponsored violence follows a series of attacks by militants—a small insurgent group, the Arakan Rohingya Salvation Army (ARSA)—in August on Myanmarese military outposts. The brutal military crackdown is ostensibly targeted at insurgents. Yet, it is unmistakably civilians who are bearing the brunt of the violence, with the UN High Commissioner calling the response “clearly disproportionate” and “without regard for basic principles of international law” (“UN”). The approach of ethnic institutionalism has

The Tax Reform India Needs

Image: Tizi A version of this article also appeared in the South China Morning Post's Young Post on Thursday, May 5.  http://yp.scmp.com/news/features/article/103398/india%E2%80%99s-economy-taking-right-steps-goods-and-service-tax India’s current prime minister, Narendra Modi, was elected in 2014 on his economic credentials and the promise that he would bring to the nation the same prosperity he brought, as chief minister, to his home state of Gujarat.  The keystone of Modi’s economic policy is a nationwide goods-and-service tax (GST), intended to streamline the myriad state and central-government levies currently encumbering business in the country.   Under the prevailing tax regime, multiple layers of tax are imposed on the same good, and interstate trade is complicated by varying tax rates between states. Transporting goods across state borders can entail long waiting times to resolve tax matters, and the plethora of obscure charges leaves ample room for co

Where Lurks the Next Crisis?

Photo: SCMP Optimism flows freely through the markets today. Asset prices are at record highs: investors are happier than ever to throw money at barely profitable technology companies, debt issuances from dubious companies and volatile governments, and anything blockchain related—from Bitcoin to Ethereum to Insanecoin, which does actually exist.     Most observers think that the coin mania is a bubble waiting to burst. But bears have been calling the whole market a bubble for a while, predicting an end to the years-long economic recovery and stock market boom. The old joke goes that economists have called seven of the last two recessions. It still rings true. Doomsayers have been convinced of a market crash since the post-recession recovery had barely gotten on its legs. But with things as they are today, are we on a path toward crisis?   I will not engage in the perilous business of trying to predict when the next economic downturn or market tumble will occur. Any such p